This post begins where the preceding post ended. I suggested there that conditions most favourable to human
flourishing would emerge in “self-organizing and self-governing societies” in
which each person “is first his or her own governor and is then
responsible for fashioning mutually productive relationships with others”. That is the description of self-organizing and
self-governing societies provided by Vincent Ostrom in The Meaning of Democracy and the Vulnerability of Democracies
(1997, p 84).
Ostrom argued that
it is “within families and other institutional arrangements characteristic of
neighbourhood, village, and community life that citizenship is learned and
practiced for most people most of the time”. This is where people learn to be
self-governing, by learning how to live and work with others. (p x)
He explained that
in face-to-face relationships associated with activities entered voluntarily
for mutual benefit people also learn to exercise power with others rather than power over
others. The exercise of power with
others implies a willingness to take account of the interest of others in
"patterns of social accountability." The democratic form of
governance that evolves under those circumstances is likely to be characterised
by “mutual understandings grounded in common knowledge, agreeable patterns of
accountability, and mutual trust” (p 287).
Vincent Ostrom’s
views on the benefits of decentralized governance for human flourishing were
based partly on the empirical research on governance arrangements conducted
with Elinor Ostrom at the Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis at
Indiana University. Aspects covered in this research included urban policing,
irrigation systems, and forest resource management. Lin Ostrom was awarded the
Nobel Prize for her work showing that common pool resources could often be
successfully managed by user associations.
The history of
decentralized governance, particularly in the United States, also provided
Vincent Ostrom with evidence that self-governing societies were practicable. He
observed:
“The American
federalists and Tocqueville were able to conceive how democracy as a form of
government could be used to craft the architecture of authority relationships
in ways that were constitutive of what could appropriately be conceptualized as
self-governing societies. Such concepts drew on prior experiences in constituting
free cities, monastic orders, religious congregations, merchant societies,
craft guilds, associations among peasants, markets, and other patterns of
human association” (p 280).
Why have many
functions previously performed by voluntary associations and local government
been centralized, leaving citizens to be passive consumers of services with no
direct role in management? It is easy enough to identify who might benefit from
centralization. Access to central pools of funding have offered service
providers the prospect of higher pay. Bureaucrats have been offered vast
opportunities for career advancement. Centralization of funding has offered
many consumers the prospect of getting someone else to help pay for services
they consume.
Centralisation of
service delivery has also promised lower cost service provision resulting from scale
economies. However, such benefits have been offset to some extent by inefficient
work practices associated with centralized bureaucracies. Lower costs could have
been achieved with greater certainty if decentralized governance had been
retained, with service delivery contracted out to the private sector.
Some readers might suspect
that Vincent Ostrom was a reactionary, vainly seeking a return to the village
life of a bygone era. He is more appropriately viewed as a scholar seeking progress
toward a science of citizenship. In the final chapter of this book he writes
optimistically:
“A quest for
conflict resolution consistent with the reestablishment of communities of
associated relationships based again on precepts of covenantal relationships is
the way for maintaining the covenantal character of self-governing societies
through time and across generations. Such an approach is facilitative of innovations
consistent with standards of enlightenment, freedom, justice, reciprocity, and
mutual trust in patterns of order in human societies” (p 280).
It is hard to know
how sufficient numbers of citizens might eventually decide to insist that assignments of
authority under current legislation be made subject to challenge and
contestation by groups who want to be self-organizing and self-governing. Perhaps
this will emerge from the slow train wreck now occurring in bureaucracies of even the
older-established democracies as they experience increasing difficulty in meeting
the expectations of voters. To reduce costs, greater efforts may be made to provide
social safety nets in a manner consistent with contestable service delivery. Increasing
efforts may be made to involve community groups in service delivery. Volunteers,
who are still active in many areas of service delivery, may seek greater involvement
in decision-making. We may also see more community groups seeking to opt out of
centralised provision of social services to obtain services more closely attuned
to their requirements.