The graph shown above indicates that productivity growth
rates in high-income countries have declined. That decline seems evident even
if we disregard the low productivity growth in the years immediately following the
global financial crisis. (Selection of high-income countries for inclusion in
the graph was based largely on aggregate GDP.)
The productivity indicator used in the graph - multifactor
productivity (MFP) – is that part of GDP growth that cannot be explained by
changes in labour and capital inputs. It reflects the influence of
technological progress and production efficiency.
The most obvious implication of a decline in MFP growth
rates is a lower rate of growth in per capita incomes. Declines in MFP growth are
sometimes offset by more rapid growth of employment, through higher immigration,
or more rapid growth of capital stock, through higher investment levels.
However, such offsetting factors are not sustainable over the longer term.
In most instances, and in the longer term, it seems
reasonable to expect a ½ percent lower rate of growth in MPF to be reflected in
a ½ percent lower rate of growth in average incomes. Over 10 years, a decline
in average income growth from, say, 2 percent per annum to 1.5 percent per
annum would amount to the difference between a 22 percent and 16 percent increase
in income.
That is not negligible, but it doesn’t cause me a great deal
of angst. As noted previously on this blog (in a post written when I was more sceptical
about the number of countries experiencing a decline in productivity growth) the
slow-down in measured productivity growth in the U.S. and some other countries
may be attributable, in part, to difficulty in measuring the outputs of the
information and communications technologies (ICT) industries. When consumers can
download more stuff that they do not have to pay for, the quality of their
lives improves, even though that isn’t reflected in average income and
consumption measurements.
It is also likely that some part of the decline in measured productivity
growth may be attributable to environmental and social regulation. I am
sceptical about the merits of much of that regulation, but I acknowledge that some
of it provides benefits to humans that should be offset against associated
income losses.
However, there is an implication of declining productivity growth
that governments and their dependents should be thinking more seriously about.
That is the potential for revenue growth to decline. Unless the revenue to GDP
ratio is raised, a lower rate of growth of MFP is likely to translate to lower growth
of government revenue. (Note that the same difficulty in measuring the outputs
of the ITC industries for productivity estimation also applies to measuring income,
sales and value added for tax purposes.)
Lower revenue growth has interesting implications in the
context of expected ongoing increases in government spending. As previously
discussed on this blog, under existing programs, substantial increases in
government spending seem likely to occur as the proportion of elderly people in
the populations of many countries continues to rise.
So, why not raise the revenue to GDP ratio by changing the
tax mix in favour of more efficient taxes that have less adverse effects on economic
incentives? The political obstacles to tax reforms have not always been insuperable,
but revenue-raising reform proposals are less likely to be supported than
revenue-neutral proposals.
Another option is to raise the revenue to GDP ratio by
raising tax rates. That is also likely to encounter political obstacles but, more importantly, the adverse effects on incentives seem likely to further reduce
productivity growth. The marginal excess burden of taxes tends to rise as the
tax rate is increased (see discussion here).
Yet another option is to let public debt continue to rise
and hope debt servicing doesn’t become too much of a problem. We may actually see
some problems emerging with that strategy over the next few years with
increased public debt incurred in response to COVID-19. Perhaps central banks will
succumb to government urging to over-stimulate economies to allow the “inflation
tax” to reduce debt to GDP ratios. However, that would make ongoing debt
accumulation a more costly strategy because it would result in high interest rates
and thus higher costs of debt servicing over the longer term.
We haven’t considered debt default, but you have to be
desperate to consider that!
My point is that governments and their dependents do not
have any easy options available to adjust to an ongoing decline in productivity
growth.
Economists advising governments will likely suggest that the
best way forward is adoption of a package of reforms (including tax reforms) to
raise productivity growth, combined with action to prune government spending. What
governments will do, however, will depend to a large extent on the relative
political power of different interest groups. In most countries, that seems to
me likely to point more toward spending cuts than toward productivity-increasing
reforms.
So, it seems reasonable to speculate that declining growth
in productivity will be ongoing and result in cuts in government spending in
policy areas where political resistance is likely to be weakest. Which policy
areas are likely to be most affected?
No comments:
Post a Comment