The story of cultural change that Edmund Phelps tells in Mass Flourishing has a happy beginning and a sad ending.
Phelps’ cultural story of the advent of rapid economic
growth in Britain and America in the 19th century is much like that
of Joel Mokyr and Deidre McCloskey (discussed here and here). The main
difference is Phelps’ greater emphasis on grassroots innovation within firms.
Phelps makes a strong case that Joseph Schumpeter, famous
for his theory of entrepreneurship, over-emphasized the importance of exogenous
scientific discoveries (external to innovating firms) as a source of
innovation. Phelps probably goes too far in downplaying scientific advances,
but his story about the importance of grassroots innovation to the emerging
modern economies seems highly plausible. He suggests:
“a modern economy turns people who are close to the economy,
where they are apt to be struck by new commercial ideas, into the investigators
and experimenters who manage the innovation process from development and, in
many cases, adoption as well” (p 26).
Phelps describes a modern economy as “a vast imaginarium – a
space for imagining new products and methods, imagining how they might be made,
imagining how they might be used” (p 27).
A substantial part of the book is devoted to a
discussion of socialism, as practiced in the Soviet Union, and corporatism, as
practiced in Italy and Germany in the 1930s. The contemporary relevance of that
discussion become relevant later in the book in his discussion of reasons for
the decline in productivity growth that seems to have occurred in the U.S.
since the 1960s.
Phelps’ focus on the U.S. economy as the main driver of
technological progress seems appropriate. He notes that European countries
experienced high productivity growth while playing the technological catch-up
game, but their productivity growth has generally been lower than in the U.S.
in recent decades. He attributes their lack of dynamism to ongoing corporatism
over the decades since World War II. The classical corporatist model -
involving state direction of industry and promotion of solidarity and social
responsibility – has been augmented with codetermination of labour and capital (instead
of owner-control) and stakeholderism (instead of a focus on income generation).
The author suggests that corporatism has also grown in the
United States. Industries that have been subject to government policy interventions
have been affected by a new populist type of corporatism as businesses have
sought to use their political influence to mould government regulation to their
advantage. The result is a “densely interconnected system of mutually
beneficial relationships between private and public’, which tends “to redirect
the economy’s innovation toward politicians”. He notes that supporters refer to
that system as industry policy and detractors refer to it as corporate welfare.
It should be referred to as rent-seeking.
The cultural change that Phelps sees as leading to a decline
in economic dynamism is not fully reflected in changes in economic freedom
indexes. He sees a deterioration in the “core functioning” of modern economies.
This involves, among other things:
- Managerialism, short-termism and the rise of a “money culture” in business, with wealth-seeking turning people away from innovation.
- A rise in the litigiousness of American society - people who devote their time and energy to suing one another have less time and energy for innovation.
- Excessive patent protection resulting in an economy clogged with patents – “a creator of a new method might require as many lawyers as engineers to proceed”.
- More people aspiring to attain social station rather than to achieve something.
- Adolescent culture – less willingness to accept temporary austerity in the quest for achievement; less ability to concentrate intensely (unable to resist distractions of social media).
- A resurgence of traditional values putting more pressure on business to allow people to work from home etc.
Has this cultural change in U.S. business caused a decline
in the long-term productivity growth rate? If so, what can be done about it?
In a series of posts written in 2015, I was sceptical that
there had been a decline in long term productivity growth. I suggested that the
slow-down in measured productivity growth in the U.S. and some other countries
may be attributable, in part, to difficulty in measuring the outputs of the
information and communications technologies (ICT) industries. I also noted
research findings suggesting a technological diffusion problem, rather than a
slow-down in technological advances, with productivity growth of global
frontier firms remaining relatively robust.
The addition of a few more years of data seems to lend support
to the view of the historical pessimists that there has been a long-term
decline in U.S. productivity growth. And Phelps’s cultural change explanation
does seem plausible.
Unfortunately, the remedies that Phelps offers are
less plausible. He suggests that governments can act to restore dynamism if
they become aware of its importance and gain some practical knowledge of how
innovation is generated. He suggests:
“Nations will have to push back against the resurgence of
traditional values that have been suffocating in recent decades and revive the
modern values that stirred people to go boldly forth toward lives of richness”.
Edmund Phelps seems to be hoping that a reinvented corporatism, perhaps
inspired by the starship Enterprise, will foster grassroots
innovation and be less prone to rent-seeking than the industry policies it
replaces. Good luck with that!
I prefer to put my faith in the potential for new technologies
to disrupt and subvert populist corporatism.
No comments:
Post a Comment