Cartoon by Peter Nicholson: from this site
Robert Sugden explains his use of the term ‘contractarian’
thus:
“the most fundamental
characteristic of this perspective is that a recommendation is addressed to a
set of individuals, showing those individuals how they can coordinate their
behaviour to achieve mutual benefit."
This post is prompted by my reading of his book, The Community of Advantage, reviewed on this blog a few weeks ago.
Sugden’s adoption of a contractarian approach was inspired
by the work of James Buchanan, in which social arrangements are assessed from
the several viewpoints of individual members of society considered as potential
parties to a social contract.
Contractarian reasoning implies a baseline of non-agreement
from which benefit is measured. For agreement to occur, each party to a
potential agreement must recognize that, for all the parties severally,
agreement is more beneficial than the status quo.
Contractarian reasoning is readily applied in considering
adoption of general rules. When individuals consider adoption of a general rule,
a veil of uncertainty about future circumstances often makes it difficult for
them to assess where their interests might lie. They become more likely to identify
as an “average” citizen than a member of a narrow interest group.
Sugden contrasts the model of contractarian reasoning with
two other approaches to normative economics, the model of the benevolent autocrat and the model of public reasoning. He suggests that each of these
different approaches to provision of public policy advice, may be appropriate,
depending on the circumstances.
When economists employ the benevolent autocrat model, they are providing executive
decision-makers with their best judgements about what should be done. In
stylized terms, Sugden suggests that they are implicitly saying: “If I were an
impartially benevolent autocrat, this is what I would do”. In my experience, when
economic advisors employed by governments are striving to be their best selves,
they tailor their advice to the values and priorities of the governments they
are serving. That doesn’t mean that bureaucrats should attempt to ‘second-guess’
political reactions in providing advice. As Roger Kerr pointed out, soon after
leaving the New Zealand Treasury to become executive director of the New
Zealand Business Roundtable, attempts to second-guess political reactions “can
lead to a narrowing of policy options” and does less than justice to those
politicians who are prepared “to tell the story like it is”. Roger explained:
“Economists of all people should be conscious that the
performance of bureaucrats in trying to pick winners and losers in the
policy-advice market is likely to be as unimpressive as in the industrial
domain – and for much the same reasons, namely the lack of information and
incentives. Perceived political constraints are not always immutable. They can
be shifted by reasoned analysis and well-constructed strategies for policy
change, developed by interaction between political managers and technical
advisers” (Roger Kerr, ‘Ideas, interests, experience and the economic adviser’,
World Economy, 10 (2) June 1987).
The model of public
reasoning provides a stylized view of politics as an arena for debate about
the public good, where the participants strive to deploy impartial and reasoned
argument. By contrast, in the real world, many participants in public debate on
economic policy strive to deploy arguments to advance their own interests. Members
of the economics profession who participate in such debates have potential to
play an important role in ensuring that the merits and demerits of the
arguments advanced are subjected to appropriate public scrutiny. That role has
been made part of the public policy advisory process in Australia by being
embodied in the public inquiry system of the Productivity Commission and its
predecessor organisations.
My mention of the ‘economics profession’ brings to mind some
provocative comments of Ludwig von Mises, an eminent Austrian economist, about
professional economists:
“By virtue of their connection with definite parties and
pressure groups, eager to acquire special privileges, they become one-sided.
They shut their eyes to the remoter consequences of the policies they are
advocating. With them nothing counts but the short-run concerns of the group
they are serving. The ultimate aim of their efforts is to their clients prosper
at the expense of other people. They are intent upon convincing themselves that
the fate of mankind coincides with the short-run interests of their group. They
try to sell this idea to the public …” (Human
Action, fourth revised edition 1996, p 869).
I disagree with Mises description of such conduct as
professional. It is unprofessional for economists to sell their souls to
interest groups. It doesn’t matter how much knowledge of economics they might
have, those who sell their souls are not behaving like members of an honourable
profession.
Improving policy
transparency
Some people with institutional expertise in public policy
development have suggested that the advisory role of economists should be more
akin to provision of information than normative advice. Bill Carmichael, a
former chairman of the Industries Assistance Commission (a predecessor
organisation to Australia’s Productivity Commission) argued for greater efforts
to improve ‘policy transparency’ – to improve public understanding of the
economic effects of policies that assist particular groups at the expense of
the broader community. With reference to trade protection policies, he argued:
“Public availability of information about the effects, on
national welfare, of responses which avert adjustment to economic change would
improve domestic understanding and narrow the range of disagreement about what
policy responses are appropriate. While it would not eliminate resistance to
change by those who will be adversely affected, it would enable the grounds for
such resistance to be weighed against the community-wide effects” (W B
Carmichael, ‘National Interest and International Trade Negotiations’, The World Economy, 9 (4) December 1986).
Bill’s reference to ‘national welfare’ might raise
tangential issues in the minds of some readers about the impossibility of
aggregating, or averaging, the welfare of different individuals in a meaningful
way, and the value judgements that are involved in using per capita GDP, or any
other measure of income, as an indicator of welfare. In order to avoid getting
bogged down in such issues, I interpret ‘national welfare’ as code for ‘the
opportunities available, individually and collectively, to members of the
community’.
When economists view their role as providing information
publicly on the impact of policy change on opportunities available to various
groups in a community, it seems to me that they are adopting something close to
a contractarian approach to provision of policy advice. Such information
enables the various groups affected to obtain a better understanding of how
they are likely to be affected by policy change. Nevertheless, a public policy process
of weighing the interests of those adversely affected by change against the
interests of broader groups is likely to fall short of the ideal of a
contractarian negotiation because the outcomes are unlikely to receive
unanimous support. Unanimity is rarely possible since those adversely affected by
change often have a strategic interest in withholding their support in the hope
of obtaining a better outcome from the process. Perhaps the most that can be
hoped for is that by the time policy decisions are made, the process will have
persuaded those adversely affected by change that they are unlikely to benefit
from lobbying to have the decisions reversed.
Compensation
Robert Sugden suggests that contractarian advisors have a
better chance of achieving unanimous support for policy change if they give
attention to compensation. When a policy proposal imposes significant harms on
a group of individuals, the addition of compensation payments may have
potential to make it mutually beneficial. Unfortunately, Sugden doesn’t discuss the
potential for those opposed to change to negotiate strategically in a context
where policy outcomes are likely to be strongly influenced by the political
muscle of narrow interest groups. When governments seek to negotiate
compensation packages with powerful interest groups, they risk putting the rest
of the community in a position somewhat akin to seeking to negotiate a settlement
with an extortionist. The above cartoon relating to negotiations for
deregulation of the Australian sugar industry illustrates the problem. After receiving
substantial adjustment assistance to gain acceptance for deregulation about a
decade ago, the industry has since been re-regulated.
Nevertheless, it is possible to cite instances where compensation
payments do seem to have enabled better policy outcomes to be achieved in
contractarian policy negotiations. In an article published a couple of years
ago, reviewing literature on agricultural adjustment in Australia, Geoff
Edwards, and I expressed the view that “economists advocating adjustment
assistance during the 1970s helped shift the focus of agricultural policy in
Australia away from price support and input subsidies, leading to greater
acceptance of policies to facilitate adjustment rather than to impede it”. We concluded that “adjustment assistance can
sometimes enable less efficient and less equitable forms of assistance to be
avoided” (Geoff Edwards and Winton Bates, ‘Antipodean agricultural and resource
economics at 60: agricultural adjustment’, Australian
Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 60, pp 573-589).
Conclusions
So, when can economists adopt a contractarian approach to
provision of public policy advice? My experience leads me to think that a contractarian
approach has been used effectively in considering changes in the ‘rules of the
game’ relating to economic policy in some countries. During the 1980s and 90’s,
some economists in Australia and New Zealand adopted important elements of a contractarian
approach in successfully proposing trade liberalisation, privatisation of
public enterprises, regulatory reforms and government spending restraint. The
focus of analysis was the potential for changes in the ‘rules of the game’ to improve
the opportunities generally available to community members. Reports were
published with a view to obtaining broad community support for changes in the
rules. Many influential opinion leaders were receptive to the view that the
rules of the game needed to be changed in order to avert looming economic
disaster.
For reasons expressed elsewhere on this blog (for example
here and here) I think the democratic political processes of western countries
have been corrupted so much over the last few decades that in the event of a
future economic crisis it is unlikely to be possible to implement reforms to prevent
emergence of widespread economic misery. I doubt whether use of a contractarian
approach to policy advice will help much in this context, but such an approach
is still more likely to be successful than the alternatives available. The best
contractarian advice I can offer to individuals is to reduce your dependence on
government as far as possible, and to seek out opportunities for mutually
beneficial interactions that do not involve governments.
Over the next few decades, I expect that economists adopting
a contractarian approach will play an increasingly important role in helping
people to use new technology to negotiate mutually beneficial agreements to obtain
what they want without government involvement. I will write more about that
later.
2 comments:
Winton: On a separate though related topic in that it involves discussion of economic policy, I've been for some months reading Martin Wolf's 2014 book, The Shifts and the Shock: What We've Learned - and Have Still to Learn - from the Financial Crisis. Lacking deep economics knowledge I find it a tough read. However, some of the finest books for me are tough to read. Often I gain recognition of that in the downhill run of a book.
I had that appreciation of Wolf's thinking today reading pages 182 to 184.
Wolf there described three transformations or underlying drivers for the shift that took place from say the early 1970s to 2014, and I don't think it has changed that much to January 2019. These are three shifts he frames succinctly.
(1) ECONOMIC LIBERALISATION SHIFT, not just in capitalist economies (with privatisation pushed by Margaret Thatcher and Ronald Reagan) but also in India, China after it embraced change from 1978 with Deng Xiaoping, and countries of the former Soviet Union. After the shift trade in services was liberalised to a degree that had not been the case before. Finance crossed borders more freely. The Maastricht Treaty was ratified in 1993 moving towards abolition of exchange controls and the EU currency union launched in 1999. The World Trade Organisation was formed and China joined in 2001.
(2) TECHNOLOGY SHIFT, less so in transport (eg with improved container ships) but especially in information and communications technologies, contributing to greater and faster know-how transfers, eg the transfer of manufacturing processes and technologies to developing economies.
(3) AGING SHIFT, with aging populations, especially in developed economies such as Germany and Japan, resulting in new economic imbalances. Very interestingly Wolf links the "chronically weak demand" that resulted from aging populations to "prolonged fiscal deficites (as in Japan) or by large current-account surpluses (as in Germany, the Netherlands and other northern European countries).
Regarding these three shifts Wolf goes onto state: "These forces in turn help explain the low real rates of interest before 2007 and the still lower real rates after the crisis, which was caused in large part by the policy responses to pre-crisis recessionary forces."
Thank you for your post, it inspired the above note taking, pulling together thinking on what may come next and what policy responses are needed by individuals, organisations, nation-states and global organisations.
Thanks for your comment Noric.
I haven’t read that book by Martin Wolf. It sounds interesting. I have read quite a lot of his stuff in the FT over the years, and have been most impressed.
I actually met Martin in London in the early 1980s when he was associated with an organisation called the Trade Policy Research Centre. I recall that we had a pleasant chat about the strong links between business people in Britain and Europe.
Post a Comment