“THOMAS GRADGRIND, sir. A man of realities. A man of facts
and calculations. A man who proceeds upon the principle that two and two are
four, and nothing over, and who is not to be talked into allowing for anything
over. Thomas Gradgrind, sir - peremptorily Thomas - Thomas Gradgrind. With a
rule and a pair of scales, and the multiplication table always in his pocket,
sir, ready to weigh and measure any parcel of human nature, and tell you
exactly what it comes to. It is a mere question of figures, a case of simple
arithmetic. You might hope to get some other nonsensical belief into the head
of George Gradgrind, or Augustus Gradgrind, or John Gradgrind, or Joseph
Gradgrind (all supposititious, non-existent persons), but into the head of Thomas
Gradgrind - no, sir!
In such terms Mr. Gradgrind always mentally introduced
himself, whether to his private circle of acquaintance, or to the public in
general.” Charles Dickens, Hard Times, Chapter2.
I'm not like that. However, an interest in happiness research may seem to many people to
imply an obsession with measuring, calculating and attempting to understand
things that are not meant to be understood.
Perhaps trying to understand what makes people happy is a bit like trying to understand why jokes are funny. It isn’t obvious that an understanding of what makes jokes funny would be much help to anyone in telling jokes, or how an understanding of what makes people happy would help anyone to become happier.
Perhaps trying to understand what makes people happy is a bit like trying to understand why jokes are funny. It isn’t obvious that an understanding of what makes jokes funny would be much help to anyone in telling jokes, or how an understanding of what makes people happy would help anyone to become happier.
It is fairly easy to explain how I came to be interested in happiness
research, so I will begin by writing about that. In my work as an economist I spent
more than a few decades considering what government policies were likely to
advance the well-being of the people in the countries where I have lived and worked (mainly Australia and New Zealand. It seemed
fairly obvious that the vast majority of Australians and New Zealanders wanted
higher incomes, so it was reasonable to assume that would improve their
well-being. If someone questioned whether higher incomes would make people any
happier, my defence was that economists should be in the business of making it
possible for people to have happier lives rather than advising them how to
spend their money.
At the same time, I could not help becoming interested in
the puzzle of why happiness surveys showed little or no increase in average happiness
ratings in high income countries over several decades while average income
levels rose substantially. This is of course Easterlin’s puzzle - named after
the economist Richard Easterlin.
I stopped being puzzled once I understood that happiness
surveys measure emotional well-being - a component of well-being rather than
the whole package. There is no reason to expect the value that people place on physical
health, education, housing and safety, among other things, to be fully
reflected in measures of emotional well-being.
Emotional well-being is strongly related to self-esteem,
optimism and the feeling of being in control of one’s life – none of which would
be expected to be strongly influenced by further increases in incomes in
high-income countries.
It is true, of course, that when people see higher incomes as the pathway to emotional
bliss they are unlikely to be satisfied with one pot of gold - even if they find the end of a rainbow. But most people seem to make sensible
choices. They might seek a higher income if that is necessary to pursue objectives that they consider to be worthwhile. For many people,
higher incomes are incidental to career objectives. There is no reason to expect people to stop trying to achieve more in life just because they
are satisfied with their current standard of living.
It seems to me that if we are interested in measuring
well-being, then the survey measures of happiness are just one of the items we
should look at. I favour the approach taken by the OECD in its Better Life Index.
However, an indicator
approach doesn’t give economists a value-free measure of well-being. It leaves
open the question of what weights should be given to the various component
indexes. The OECD leaves the value judgement in the hands of the users of its index.
That is more appropriate than having researchers assign weights, but it would
be good to see how weights might need to differ to reflects the different values of people in
different parts of the world. In my view the Better Life Index should be
accompanied by illustrative weights derived from a values survey.
So, one of the reasons why
I am interested in happiness research is apparent from what I have written. Happiness
research is relevant to measurement of human well-being and that is relevant to
economic policy.
I am particularly
interested in the relationship between freedom and flourishing. Do government
restrictions on individual freedom – in the wars against drug taking, smoking, alcohol,
obesity, overwork etc. - actually have the desired effect of enabling people to
have happier lives? I don’t think so. The policies adopted by governments seem
designed to make people less happy in an attempt to get them to adopt healthier
lifestyles, but I don’t know where to find the evidence to prove it.
In any case, that is only
part of the story. My interest in happiness research is not always closely
related to government policy. Some of my recent posts have taken me into the
relationship between life satisfaction and the incidence of negative emotional
experience. I am not sure why I am interested in such matters. Nevertheless, it seems more satisfying than spending my time trying to understand what makes jokes funny.
No comments:
Post a Comment