I was delighted when I first noticed that Human
Development Report 2014 has looked at the question of how poor people in
developing countries can be made less vulnerable and more resilient in the face
of natural disasters, commodity price instability and other threats to their
well-being. In turning its attention to vulnerability and resilience the United Nations
Development Programme (UNDP) has recognized the progress that has occurred in
reducing world poverty in recent decades.
However, I am appalled that the UNDP has adopted an approach
that is likely to lead to lead to greater welfare dependency and increased government
debt in developing countries, and inevitably make the poor people in those
countries more vulnerable to extreme poverty when fiscal restraint has to be
re-imposed. There is something very peculiar about the idea that people can
become more resilient by being made dependent upon unsustainable government
largesse. The UNDP seems to have an obsessive desire to encourage developing
countries to adopt the most expensive kind of welfare system imaginable.
At this point you probably think that I must be
exaggerating. If so, you are wrong! The report does not argue for provision of
a targeted safety net to assist those most in need of help at time they most
need that assistance. In fact, it rejects that approach explicitly in favour of
universal provision of basic social services such as education and health care.
The authors argue:
“Universal coverage of basic social services is not only imperative
– it is also possible at an early stage of development. And recent evidence
shows that it can be achieved in less than a decade” (p 85).
The authors recite the view that when social benefits are
targeted, “the middle class and elites are less willing to fund them through
taxes”. They obviously see little merit
in public policy transparency. They also over-estimate their ability to pull
the wool over the eyes of middle and upper-income voters. Such voters have not
been backward in shifting the burden of funding universal welfare back to low
income earners via taxes on wages or goods and services (as in Scandinavian
countries) or in shifting it forward to future generations through increases in
public debt (as in many other high-income countries).
When the authors discuss policies to promote full employment
they show some recognition that a somewhat different approach might be
appropriate in developing countries. They recognize a need for policies to
address the vulnerabilities of people engaged in traditional agricultural
activities and informal sectors. For example, they mention the role of
micro-credit schemes, improved small-scale technologies and support for farmer
cooperatives.
I was hoping to see some innovative thinking about food
security in the report, but I didn’t find any. The issue is mentioned in the
discussion of agricultural trade liberalization, where it is in the “too hard”
basket. There is recognition that “spikes in the prices of food and other
commodities are adding to hunger and starvation for the poor and vulnerable”,
without consideration of how this could be avoided. There is recognition that
farmers in developing countries often have to compete with subsidized agricultural
products from developed countries, again without providing any suggestions
about how this could be avoided. And there is this peculiar recommendation:
“Agricultural liberalization needs to be selective in targeting goods mainly
exported by developing countries to avoid increasing prices of food staples of
developing countries”. So much for free trade, or even fair trade!
Actually, apart from that example of absurdity, I found the
section on trade in Chapter 5 of the report to be one of the more sensible
parts of the report.
While I am in a positive frame of mind I should also mention
that the report has some informative diagrams showing progress in reducing
world poverty. For example, Figure 2.6 (page 41) shows that for most countries the
poorest 40 percent of the population have enjoyed more rapid consumption than
the population as a whole over the period 2005-10. However, when the authors wrote about that Figure, what they emphasized was that consumption for those at the
poorest end of the distribution has been slower than for the population as a
whole in some countries where inequality has been high or rising. The three
countries they cite as examples are Malaysia, China and Uganda. That seems to
me to be grossly unfair to China and Uganda; in those countries, growth in
consumption at the poorest end of the distribution has been much the same as for
the population as a whole.
It was almost inevitable that the UNDP would
produce a disappointing report about how to reduce vulnerabilities and build
resilience in developing countries. People who work for international agencies are always subject to the temptation to see themselves as architects of human development. It would be overly optimistic to expect anyone
writing a report for the UNDP to show an understanding the bottom-up processes
through which economic development has tended to lead to growth of emancipative values and progressively greater efforts to protect vulnerable people from
misfortunes.
The authors of the report seem to have hopes that the approach
they advocate will influence international debate about the post 2015
development agenda, which is to follow the Millennium Development Goals. In my
view their report should be ignored. The approach the authors advocate is a recipe for
a return to more widespread poverty and misery throughout the world.
1 comment:
Post a Comment